There are no ways to eliminate fiscal deficits that are easy on Canadians and good for politicians. The availability of social program benefits is considered to be a right and woe politicians who favour cutting them. Spending that serves special interests cannot be cut without incurring the wrath of its beneficiaries. Canadians hate tax increases and politicians know it.
However, there is a simple way to balance budgets and avoid all of these problems: reduce significantly the level of immigration. Foreigners do not vote in Canadian elections.
Reduced immigration reduces fiscal imbalances because Canada’s welfare state provides social benefits to immigrants worth much more than what they pay in taxes. The costs do not show up in any official budgets, but they are large and will grow as more immigrants are admitted.
The costs stem from the fact that immigrants and their families receive on average the same government benefits as other Canadians – education for their children, health-care, employment insurance and welfare benefits. In addition, immigrant families are provided with special services to help them integrate into Canadian society and the economy – language instruction, settlement and legal advice and housing subsidies.
These costs are offset to some extent by the taxes paid by immigrants. The problem is that they pay considerably less than Canadians for two main reasons. First, Canada’s personal income tax system is very progressive. The top ten percent of all income tax filers pay about one half of all taxes while the bottom half of filers pay only about 5 percent. Second, recent immigrants after arrival have much lower earnings than Canadians: On average their earnings are 65 percent in the first year, rise gradually over the next 9 years to a maximum of 80 percent of the earnings of Canadian workers with similar demographic characteristics.
These two facts imply that few of the recent immigrants are in the top decile, many are in the bottom half of income tax payers and that their asset holdings are relatively small. Using these basic facts, I have estimated that on average immigrants pay 21 percent of the income taxes, only 80 percent of sales and other taxes and even smaller percentages of corporate income and property taxes than do Canadians.
Attaching dollar figures to these percentages implies that immigrants who arrived in 1990, on average in 2000 consumed government services worth $6,300 more than they paid in taxes; the 216,000 immigrants who arrived in 1990 generated a net transfer of $1.36 billion in 2000 while all of the immigrants who arrived during the last decade of the century, in the year 2000 generated transfers to themselves worth about $18.3 billion and will do so for in coming years.
The preceding calculations are rough and based on many assumptions, but they are the only ones available. More studies may show that the net costs are higher or lower, but it is clear they exist, are likely to be substantial and will continue to persist and grow if present immigration policies are continued.
But will immigrants not bring benefits to Canadians that match or even exceed these fiscal costs? Consider the following types of alleged benefits.
First, the economy benefits as immigrants fill jobs that other Canadians do not want or are not trained for. The problem is that these immigrants lower the wages of other Canadians competing with them and cause poverty levels to be higher than they would be otherwise and requiring more spending on anti-poverty programs.
Most fundamentally, in the absence of immigrants, there would be no long-lasting labour or skills shortages because wages on presently undesirable jobs would rise until they are filled by Canadians; higher wages for skilled workers would encourage more Canadians to get the needed education and training; and employers would invest more capital to raise labour productivity, which would allow them to maintain profits while paying workers the higher wages.
Second, many people believe that immigrants provide an easy solution to the looming crisis of unfunded liabilities for public health care and pension programs. Simulations using official estimates of population dynamics show that to maintain the present ratio of retired to working people in Canada in the year 2050 alone would require 7 million immigrants and a population level of 165 million. Canada could not absorb immigrants in such large numbers and might well not be able to recruit them. There are much less costly methods for defusing the pending crisis of unfunded liabilities, such as increasing the age of retirement.
Third, immigrants are believed to generate economies of scale that lower the average cost of infrastructure like roads and municipal services for all Canadians. This benefit from immigration existed in the past. In recent years and in the future, immigrants add significantly to congestion, pollution and the prices of scarce land and housing.
The magnitude of these problems is not widely recognized but may be gleaned from the fact that currently immigrant families arriving in the BC Lower Mainland every week of the year need 200 new housing units that require electricity, water and sewers. These families send children to school, put cars on the road and use public transit. It is ironic that meeting these needs of immigrants results in labour shortages that in turn are used to justify further immigration.
Finally, some Canadians believe immigration should continue in the spirit of the country’s proud tradition of helping poor and oppressed people find a land of opportunity. This feel-good benefit of immigration cannot be measured, but should rationally be compared to the costs it brings. The estimate above suggests that this benefit is very expensive indeed.
The possible reduction of immigration levels to balance the budget in the future is not discussed publicly by politicians, who fear the resultant loss of immigrant votes. But these politicians should consider whether the loss is as great as is commonly assumed since recent immigrants in surveys often express the view that immigration should be reduced. They should also ponder whether the loss of immigrant votes really is greater than the loss of votes due to spending cuts and tax increases that are mandated by the present fiscal imbalances.
Wednesday, April 28, 2010
Tuesday, April 13, 2010
The Trouble with Climate Model Forecasts
In the light of recent developments, it is surprising that there have been no revelations from insiders about the misuse of sophisticated computer models, which have played a pivotal role in the International Panel on Climate Change’s dire forecasts of catastrophic climate changes. The truth is that while some aspects of these models involve objective science, they also rely heavily on personal judgments so that their results “prove” nothing and it is foolish to use them as a justification for any policies.
The problems associated with climate models are illustrated by the recent response of a government meteorologist to a request for a forecast of the temperature during the week leading up to the Olympic Winter games in Vancouver. The answer was “It depends on what forecasting models you look at. Some are predicting continued warm, some cooler weather.”
There a several reasons for problems with complex computer models.
First, they consist of large numbers of equations that mirror relationships between variables like land and ocean temperatures at different latitudes, greenhouse gas levels, cloud covers, seasonal variations in sun intensity, periodic changes in ocean currents and many others. The equations involve feedbacks, lags and interdependencies among the variables that result in complexities that the human mind cannot track directly and which are the main justification for the use of ever speedier and larger computers.
Second, many of the equations, the interrelationships and the lags are based on imperfect empirical information. Some of this information is biased through manipulations of the sort revealed by the emails among the staff of IPCC. Many of the parameters of the equations and forecasts of levels and rates of change are assumed rather than based on scientifically rigorous projections.
Third, the number of variables affecting the global climate and found in the equations and interrelationships is extremely large, if not infinite. Modellers can use only a limited, albeit growing number of them, employing personal judgments rather than scientific criteria in the selection.
Fourth, some of the influences on the earth’s climate are random, like volcanic eruptions, fluctuations in atmospheric ozone levels and cosmic radiation from the sun and other celestial bodies. It is obvious that they cannot be incorporated systematically in the models and can easily invalidate all estimates based on more predictable relationships.
Because of these and some other problems associated with the construction and use of complex climate change models, the results are highly uncertain and can easily be manipulated to serve ulterior objectives, as is suggested by Lowell Wood, a distinguished scientist who is intimately familiar with these models. In an interview with Stephen Levitt and Stephen Dubner, the authors of the book Super Freakonomics, he said “Everybody turns their knobs so they aren’t the outlier, because the outlying model is going to have difficulty getting funded.” By “turning their knobs” he means adjusting models until they are in a range consistent with what the financial sponsors of the work expect.
In this context it is worth noting a close similarity between economic and climate forecasting models. During the 1960s, the economic models were expected to become increasingly reliable instruments for forecasting inflation, economic growth, unemployment and other measures of economic well being, using ever more equations, variables, estimating techniques and powerful computers. Lawrence Klein, one of the pioneers in the development of these forecasting models was honoured with a Nobel Prize.
We now know that in spite of expensive efforts to perfect these models, they are of very limited use. The forecasts they generate are routinely adjusted through ad hoc changes until they are consistent with intuitive outcomes. Canada’s Department of Finance was accused of manipulating the results of its models to justify politically motivated fiscal budgets, which prompted the new Finance Minister Paul Martin in 1994to use the average of private economic forecasts as a base for his budget. The differences in these forecasts are themselves evidence of the subjectivity involved in the construction of the models on which they are based.
It is about time to treat both economic and climate change models with equal degrees of scepticism and that their authors admit to the use of ad hoc adjustments to produce outcomes that are consistent with the expectations of their sponsors. The scientists producing these models owe humanity this much as their work serves as the justification for global climate change policies that may well be more expensive than any global collective effort in history.
The problems associated with climate models are illustrated by the recent response of a government meteorologist to a request for a forecast of the temperature during the week leading up to the Olympic Winter games in Vancouver. The answer was “It depends on what forecasting models you look at. Some are predicting continued warm, some cooler weather.”
There a several reasons for problems with complex computer models.
First, they consist of large numbers of equations that mirror relationships between variables like land and ocean temperatures at different latitudes, greenhouse gas levels, cloud covers, seasonal variations in sun intensity, periodic changes in ocean currents and many others. The equations involve feedbacks, lags and interdependencies among the variables that result in complexities that the human mind cannot track directly and which are the main justification for the use of ever speedier and larger computers.
Second, many of the equations, the interrelationships and the lags are based on imperfect empirical information. Some of this information is biased through manipulations of the sort revealed by the emails among the staff of IPCC. Many of the parameters of the equations and forecasts of levels and rates of change are assumed rather than based on scientifically rigorous projections.
Third, the number of variables affecting the global climate and found in the equations and interrelationships is extremely large, if not infinite. Modellers can use only a limited, albeit growing number of them, employing personal judgments rather than scientific criteria in the selection.
Fourth, some of the influences on the earth’s climate are random, like volcanic eruptions, fluctuations in atmospheric ozone levels and cosmic radiation from the sun and other celestial bodies. It is obvious that they cannot be incorporated systematically in the models and can easily invalidate all estimates based on more predictable relationships.
Because of these and some other problems associated with the construction and use of complex climate change models, the results are highly uncertain and can easily be manipulated to serve ulterior objectives, as is suggested by Lowell Wood, a distinguished scientist who is intimately familiar with these models. In an interview with Stephen Levitt and Stephen Dubner, the authors of the book Super Freakonomics, he said “Everybody turns their knobs so they aren’t the outlier, because the outlying model is going to have difficulty getting funded.” By “turning their knobs” he means adjusting models until they are in a range consistent with what the financial sponsors of the work expect.
In this context it is worth noting a close similarity between economic and climate forecasting models. During the 1960s, the economic models were expected to become increasingly reliable instruments for forecasting inflation, economic growth, unemployment and other measures of economic well being, using ever more equations, variables, estimating techniques and powerful computers. Lawrence Klein, one of the pioneers in the development of these forecasting models was honoured with a Nobel Prize.
We now know that in spite of expensive efforts to perfect these models, they are of very limited use. The forecasts they generate are routinely adjusted through ad hoc changes until they are consistent with intuitive outcomes. Canada’s Department of Finance was accused of manipulating the results of its models to justify politically motivated fiscal budgets, which prompted the new Finance Minister Paul Martin in 1994to use the average of private economic forecasts as a base for his budget. The differences in these forecasts are themselves evidence of the subjectivity involved in the construction of the models on which they are based.
It is about time to treat both economic and climate change models with equal degrees of scepticism and that their authors admit to the use of ad hoc adjustments to produce outcomes that are consistent with the expectations of their sponsors. The scientists producing these models owe humanity this much as their work serves as the justification for global climate change policies that may well be more expensive than any global collective effort in history.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)